StudySmarter: Study help & AI tools
4.5 • +22k Ratings
More than 22 Million Downloads
Free
Unlock the complex world of sequential bargaining with this comprehensive guide. You will delve into the fundamentals of sequential bargaining, its key features, and how it forms a fundamental part of managerial economics. Then, explore the game theory of sequential bargaining, its practical applications, and the intricacies of a 3-period bargaining game. Finally, unravel the concept of bargaining power in sequential games, and discover effective techniques and principles with real-life examples. Engaging in this guide promises a wealth of knowledge in Business Studies for both novices and advanced learners alike.
Explore our app and discover over 50 million learning materials for free.
Lerne mit deinen Freunden und bleibe auf dem richtigen Kurs mit deinen persönlichen Lernstatistiken
Jetzt kostenlos anmeldenNie wieder prokastinieren mit unseren Lernerinnerungen.
Jetzt kostenlos anmeldenUnlock the complex world of sequential bargaining with this comprehensive guide. You will delve into the fundamentals of sequential bargaining, its key features, and how it forms a fundamental part of managerial economics. Then, explore the game theory of sequential bargaining, its practical applications, and the intricacies of a 3-period bargaining game. Finally, unravel the concept of bargaining power in sequential games, and discover effective techniques and principles with real-life examples. Engaging in this guide promises a wealth of knowledge in Business Studies for both novices and advanced learners alike.
When it comes to decision-making and negotiations within the sphere of Managerial Economics, sequential bargaining is an essential concept.
Sequential bargaining refers to a method of negotiation where parties involved in a deal act alternately, one after another, rather than simultaneously.
Sequential bargaining, thus, is about order and timing, where each party observes the action of the preceding party before making a decision or taking action.
In sequential bargaining, the bargaining power is often not equal and is subject to the intrinsic structure of the bargaining game. Typically, the party moving first in the sequence has an advantage, although that can depend on other factors.
The precise structure of a sequential bargaining game can be represented mathematically using game theory concepts.
Sequential bargaining is distinguished by several unique features and characteristics.
Order of Moves | Pre-determined |
Observation | Decision of previous mover observed |
Bargaining Power | Influenced by order of moves |
For instance, consider a case where a company is negotiating a contract with a supplier. If the company states its conditions and prices first, it sets the "anchor" or reference point for further negotiations. The supplier can then either accept, reject, or propose a counteroffer. The company's initial offer thus influences the outcome of the negotiation.
Accordingly, understanding and strategically utilising sequential bargaining can significantly impact negotiation outcomes in managerial economics. Gain a solid comprehension of this dynamic to enhance your decision-making prowess and negotiation acumen.
Game theory, particularly sequential bargaining game theory, has substantial applications in various fields, including Business Studies. It provides a scientific approach to strategic interactions where the solution or outcome depends on the actions of all the players involved.
The keystone of sequential bargaining game theory lies within extensive form games. In these types of games, the order of moves is explicit, and players have a chance to react to the choices made by others.
To represent a sequential game, we use a decision tree, also known as a game tree, where each node (a point in the tree) represents a player's decision and each branch (connecting line) represents a player's possible actions. At the end of every possible path lies an outcome, represented as the terminal node, associated with a numeric payoff for each player.
Let's consider two players A and B. Player A moves first and has two possible actions: Up (U) and Down (D). Should player A select U, player B would then make their decision with two options: Left (L) and Right (R). Each combination leads to a different result with distinct payoffs for players A and B.
The game tree could look like this:
A / \ U D | B / \ L RThe associated payoffs might be set up such that (U,L) = \( (4,3) \), (U,R) = \( (1,1) \), and (D) = \( (2,2) \). In this setup, Player A would choose U because the worst payoff with U (1) is better than the payoff with D (2). Player B would then choose L because the payoff with L (3) is better than that with R (1). Therefore, the equilibrium of this sequential bargaining game is (U,L) with the payoff of \( (4,3) \).
Sequential bargaining game theory finds practical applications in a wide array of business scenarios. For instance, businesses often engage in sequential bargaining with suppliers, vendors, employees, and other stakeholders. Their negotiation tactics can be strategically set based on the principles of sequential bargaining game theory.
Consider a firm negotiating with a labour union. The firm, given the power dynamics, may often hold the position of the first mover. It may make the first proposal concerning wages and working conditions. The labour union, observing this, can then decide to either accept the proposal, reject it, or make a counter-proposal.
First Mover | Firm |
Proposal | Wages, Working Conditions |
Second Mover | Labour Union |
Response | Accept, Reject, Counter-proposal |
Another critical application of sequential bargaining game theory in business studies is in market entry strategies. A company planning to enter a new market may have to consider the potential reactions of incumbent firms. Through game theory analysis, the firm can anticipate potential responses and plan their market entry strategy accordingly.
In essence, sequential bargaining game theory can be used to model any situation where individuals or groups make decisions sequentially based on the actions of others. It provides a formal framework for analysing situations of strategic interdependence, enabling individuals and organisations to navigate complex decision-making scenarios more efficiently.
As you delve deeper into the study of sequential bargaining in managerial economics, you will encounter more complex scenarios, such as the 3 Period Sequential Bargaining Game. This particular game situation affords the opportunity to explore the dynamics of sequential bargaining in situations where multiple rounds of negotiations are required.
At its core, the 3 Period Sequential Bargaining Game is an expansion on the basic principles of sequential bargaining and game theory. The central premise of this bargaining game involves three distinct rounds, or periods, of strategic decision-making.
Each period or round in the game represents an opportunity for one party to propose a division of a resource and for the other party to respond. The key difference between this and a simpler sequential bargaining game is that if an agreement is not reached in the first period, the game continues into a second period, and potentially a third, until an agreement is achieved.
This game places more importance on the aspect of time and the potential for changing power dynamics over multiple rounds. For instance, if a player rejects a proposal in an early round, they may gain bargaining power in the following round as the initial proposer may be under increased pressure to reach an agreement.
To fully grasp the dynamics of a 3 Period Sequential Bargaining Game, you must keep several considerations in mind:
Imagine a company negotiating a sale price for an asset with a potential buyer. In the first round or period, the company proposes a selling price. The buyer can accept or reject this proposal. If the buyer rejects, the game moves into a second period, whereby the buyer can now propose a new price. If rejected, the third period would finally see the company proposing the last price before a deal is reached or the negotiation fails entirely. In this scenario, the dynamics present in each period could significantly influence the final sales price.
The 3 Period Sequential Bargaining Game can model various real-world business scenarios where negotiations involve several stages or rounds. Here are two relevant examples within the business context.
Labor Negotiations: This game is particularly applicable in labor negotiations, where both the employer and the labor union have strong interests in the negotiations' outcome. Suppose a company is renegotiating a contract with its employee union and has three rounds of negotiations. Each round represents a period where the company, or the union, can propose new conditions. If the proposals are not accepted in a given round, they proceed to the next until an agreement is reached, or the negotiation dissolves.
First Period | Company proposes the contract |
Second Period | Union proposes counter-contract |
Third Period | Company offers the final contract |
Mergers and Acquisitions: In a merger or acquisition, companies negotiate several terms, including the merger ratio or acquisition price. Such negotiations can extend over multiple rounds before an agreement is reached, thus applying the 3 Period Sequential Bargaining Game concept. For instance, company A initiates an offer to acquire company B. If company B rejects the initial offer, it could propose a counter-offer in the next period. Finally, Company A has the option to propose a final offer in the third period.
First Period | Company A proposes acquisition price |
Second Period | Company B proposes counter-offer |
Third Period | Company A presents final offer |
These examples illustrate the applicability of the 3 Period Sequential Bargaining Game in business settings, and how understanding its dynamics can assist in formulating strategic negotiation tactics.
In any negotiation or bargaining game, particularly in sequential games, the concept of bargaining power is widely prevalent and significantly influential. The idea of bargaining power pertains to the relative capacity of each player within the game to influence the outcome in their favour. Furthermore, an understanding of bargaining power can be critical in defining strategies and making informed decisions during the game.
In a sequential game, the concept of bargaining power has a specific application. It often relates to the temporal order of moves or the ability of a player to anticipate and strategically respond to the actions of others.
In sequential game theory, bargaining power is typically defined by two key aspects: the order of moves and informational advantages.
The order of moves refers to the sequence in which players make their decisions within the game. In sequential games, where players make decisions one after another, the player who gets to act first often has an advantage. They can set the course of the game by their initial action, which is followed by ensuing reactions from the other players. This advantage is often referred to as the first-mover advantage.
Moreover, the player acting later in the game can have the advantage of observing the decisions made by earlier movers, allowing them to make more informed decisions. This is known as the second-mover advantage.
Informational advantages pertain to how much each player knows about the game and the other players. A player equipped with more information about the preferences, payoffs or strategies of other players generally possesses greater bargaining power.
To illustrate, consider a two-player game where player A moves first, proposing a split of a pie. Player B, observing the proposal of player A, can agree to the split or reject it. In this case, player A's ability to set the terms first confers them with some bargaining power. However, player B's ability to accept or reject the proposed split also provides them with some power.
Several factors can influence the bargaining power of players in a sequential game, and these factors can play a crucial role in determining the outcomes of the game.
Time Preference | Patience levels of the player |
Nature of Payoffs | Relative payoff from game's outcome |
Information Asymmetry | Exclusive information possession |
Outside Options | Availability of alternatives |
Reputation | Past behaviour and credibility |
These factors intensively interplay in real-world scenarios, where businesses conduct negotiations that can be formalised as sequential bargaining games. For example, in labour negotiations, time preference plays a vital role where a more patient labour union can take a firm stance on their demands, thereby increasing their bargaining power. On the other hand, high information asymmetry, such as exclusive know-how of a unique production technique by the employer, can extend greater bargaining power to the employer.
Therefore, understanding these factors and their applications can significantly support businesses during negotiations, enabling more strategic decision-making by grasping the dynamics of bargaining power in sequential games.
Thriving in the world of business often necessitates negotiation and bargaining. Within such scenarios, understanding the principles and techniques of sequential bargaining can play a pivotal role. Successful utilisation of these techniques can increase the chances of securing favourable outcomes in negotiations.
In sequential bargaining, effective negotiation techniques are linked to the systematic nature of the process. Several commonly used techniques can enhance bargaining power and improve decision-making.
First-mover Advantage: Utilising the first-mover advantage involves being the initial party to make a move or deliver a proposal. This technique sets the reference point for the negotiation and guides the subsequent back-and-forth of proposals and counter-proposals.Technique | First-mover Advantage |
Description | Being the initial party to make a move or propose an offer |
Technique | Patience |
Description | Waiting and making a calculated move after assessing the first mover's action |
Technique | Information Asymmetry |
Description | Leveraging additional or superior information about the opponent's position |
Technique | Anchoring |
Description | Setting a firm initial offer to 'anchor' the negotiation |
Core principles lie at the heart of sequential bargaining. These principles can guide the implementation of techniques and influence the design of negotiation strategies.
Alternation of Roles: The foundation of sequential bargaining is the principle of alternating roles. In a negotiation, the proposer and responder roles switch back and forth, allowing for the natural flow of offer and counter-offer.Strategic Thinking: In sequential bargaining, each participant's actions depend on their expectations about the future actions of their opponents. This strategic dependence on others' actions forms a cornerstone principle of sequential bargaining.
Principle | Alternation of Roles |
Explained | Roles switch back and forth between proposer and responder in the negotiation |
Principle | Strategic Thinking |
Explained | Participants actions are influenced by expectations of future opponent actions |
Principle | Inter-temporal Linkages |
Explained | Decisions at one point in time affect future actions and outcomes |
In the business world, one often witnesses the application of sequential bargaining principles and techniques. From corporate mergers to labour negotiations, they can be observed in a myriad of contexts.
Case study 1 – Industrial Relations: In a labour negotiation scenario, a labour union and a company may engage in multiple rounds of proposal and counter-proposal concerning wages and working conditions. Here, strategies like 'anchoring' by laying out an ambitious initial proposal or 'information asymmetry' where one party possesses detailed knowledge of market wage conditions can manipulate the outcome.Case Study | Industrial Relations |
Description | Labour union and company engage in sequential bargaining over wages and working conditions |
Case Study | Mergers and Acquisitions |
Description | Companies negotiate over acquisition price, share ratios, and future business strategy |
These case studies display the extent to which sequential bargaining principles and techniques inform real-world business negotiations.
What is sequential bargaining in terms of managerial economics?
Sequential bargaining is a method of negotiation where parties involved in a deal act alternately, one after another, rather than simultaneously. It's about order and timing, where each party observes the action of the previous party before making a decision.
What are the key features of sequential bargaining?
The key features of sequential bargaining are: order of moves, where the negotiating parties move in a sequence; observation, each party observes the decisions made by the previous mover; and bargaining power, which can be influenced by the order of moves.
How does sequential bargaining potentially impact negotiation outcomes in managerial economics?
In sequential bargaining, the party moving first often has an advantage and can set the 'anchor' or reference point for further negotiations. This understanding and strategic use of sequential bargaining can significantly impact negotiation outcomes in managerial economics.
What is sequential bargaining game theory?
Sequential bargaining game theory, a part of game theory, provides a scientific approach to model strategic interactions where the outcome depends on the actions of all the players involved. It employs the method of extensive form games where players make decisions based on others' actions.
How are sequential games represented visually?
Sequential games are represented using a decision or game tree. Each point (node) in the tree represents a player's decision and each line (branch) denotes possible actions. Every potential path ends with an outcome (terminal node) with a numeric payoff for each player.
How is Sequential bargaining game theory applied in business scenarios?
Sequential bargaining game theory is used in various business scenarios like negotiations with suppliers, vendors, stakeholders, labour unions, and in deciding market entry strategies. The theory helps businesses anticipate potential responses to their actions and aids in strategic decision-making processes.
Already have an account? Log in
Open in AppThe first learning app that truly has everything you need to ace your exams in one place
Sign up to highlight and take notes. It’s 100% free.
Save explanations to your personalised space and access them anytime, anywhere!
Sign up with Email Sign up with AppleBy signing up, you agree to the Terms and Conditions and the Privacy Policy of StudySmarter.
Already have an account? Log in